Following the classification of Cooke et al. (2009), we differentiate at the next level between
one type of method based on assumptions about individual choice processes which can
be described by mathematical axioms regarding outcome ordering, and on the other hand,
methods based on social psychological theory which do not employ such rigorous restrictions
on preferences over outcomes.
The next decision encountered in selecting an appropriate method of
behavioural analysis is one based on the criteria of theoretical
assumptions employed. Approaches based on utility maximisation explain
and predict behaviour based on axiomatic mathematical models which
assume that rational individuals maximise utility. The classical
assumptions of rational choice are that given a choice set, preferences
are complete, transitive and continuous. This is a vast literature
dating back more than a century to the foundations of modern economic
thought and utilitarianism (e.g. Mill, 1863). As it is beyond the scope
of this guidance to discuss this vast literature, we limit ourselves to
a couple of approaches relevant for CCVIA. If you believe that
actor’s choice processes can be appropriately described
through the axioms of rational choice, you will be lead towards these
approaches.
On the other hand, approaches based
on social psychological
theory explain and predict behaviour through empirically-based
statistical models using cognitive variables such as motivations and
barriers for action. A prominent theory which underlies these
approaches is Protection Motivation Theory, which posits that actors
take action based on four factors: the perceived severity of a
threatening event, the perceived probability of the occurrence, the
efficacy of the recommended preventive behaviour, and the perceived
self efficacy (Rogers 1983). In the domain of CCVIA, Grothmann and Patt
(2005) draw on Protection Motivation Theory (PMT) to explain the
adaptive behaviour in case studies in Germany and Zimbabwe, finding
that adaptive actions taken are better explained through PMT than
traditional microeconomic models of decision-making.
It
is worth noting that though this decision node is essentially one of
based on theoretical assumptions, one can tentatively say that those
behaviours which appear intuitively irrational, may be more fruitfully
examined through the methods of social-psychology. For example, more
useful insights into the choice processes of the elderly regarding
drinking water during heat waves may be gained from applying social
psychological methods, than from a rational choice framework. This is
because meaning and interpretation are often important in understanding
and explaining behaviour, particularly outside of market setting, and
social psychological approaches explicitly address these aspects.
This section is based on the UNEP PROVIA guidance document |
1. | You want to identify adaptation measures. | |
2. | Your focus is on public actors and on individual actions. | |
3. | The actors' potential capacity is high, but the private actors are not adapting autonomously. | |
4. | Adaptation would not conflict with private interests. | |
5. | It is not succificient to describe actors and behaviours. | |
6. | As a next step you are faced with the question whether it is assumed that individuals' choice can be decribed by mathematical axioms. |