The concepts of real options analysis lie originally in the
financial markets. A financial option gives the investor the right, but
not the obligation, to acquire a financial asset in the future,
allowing them to observe how market conditions play out before deciding
whether to exercise the option. This transfers risk from the buyer to
the seller, making the option a valuable commodity. Options analysis
quantifies this value based on how much such a risk transfer is worth
(Black and Scholes, 1973).
The same insights are
also useful for investment in physical assets (hence
‘real’ options), in cases where there is
risk/uncertainty (McDonald and Siegel, 1986). Real options analysis
(ROA) quantifies the investment risk associated with uncertain future
outcomes. It is particularly useful when considering the value of
flexibility of investments. This might be for example flexibility over
the timing of the original capital investment, or the flexibility to
adjust the investment as it progresses over a number of stages,
allowing decision-makers to adapt, expand or scale-back the project in
response to unfolding events.
ROA typically
gives two types of result that set it apart from traditional economic
analysis. The first affects projects that are cost-efficient under a
deterministic analysis. ROA shows that sometimes it makes more sense to
wait for the outcome of new information, rather than investing
immediately. Conversely, the second type of result affects projects
which may fail a deterministic test of cost-efficiency. Under
conditions of uncertainty, it may make financial sense to start the
initial stages of the project where these are needed to keep the
overall project alive, in case its fortunes change at a later date and
it starts to look like an attractive investment option.
ROA
has been applied quite widely in the energy sector, including analysis
of mitigation options, and there are examples in the literature looking
at the uncertainty of investment under climate change policy (e.g.
Hlouskova et al. 2005: Fuss et al, 2009; Szolgayova et al 2011). As
further examples, Rothwell (2006) examined returns on
investment in nuclear plant with uncertainty over carbon prices, while
Laurikka and Koljonen (2006) looked at investment uncertainty with
future emissions trading.
Such studies show that
ROA can provide useful information to help decisions in cases of three
key conditions:
- First, the investment
decision is irreversible once taken;
- Second,
the decision-maker has some flexibility when to carry out the
investment (either in a single step, or in stages);
- Third,
the decision-maker faces uncertain conditions and by waiting
to invest they are able to gain new valuable
information regarding the success of the investment.
The
formal application of the approach (e.g. Dixit and Pindyck, 1994) is
rather complex, but the intuition of the method can be described
relatively easily.
For a simple one-off
investment opportunity which faces uncertain outcomes, it may be worth
waiting to invest at a later date when more information is gained about
the likelihood of different outcomes. Waiting can help the
decision-maker to avoid costly mistakes by allowing them to decide not
to proceed with an investment if they find themselves facing poor
investment conditions.
For waiting to be
worthwhile, the decision-maker must reasonably expect to gain valuable
information. The value of waiting will then be higher (lower) if:
- The
degree of uncertainty regarding the costeffectiveness of the project is
greater (smaller)
- The duration of the period of
waiting before information is gained is shorter (longer)
The
value of waiting needs to be balanced against the cost of waiting (see
box), because during the period of waiting, the project will not be
delivering the goods, services or other benefits it set out to achieve.
ROA
therefore provides decision-makers with a new investment criterion that
takes account of uncertainty. Projects should proceed if the project
overall seems cost-efficient and if the cumulative lost value of these
benefits during the waiting time exceeds the value of waiting.
However,
projects are usually more complex than a simple one-off investment, and
ROA can add to the understanding of how project value evolves during
the various stages of project development.
There
will often be flexibility to adapt the project as it proceeds through
these stages, for example to expand, contract, or even stop the project
altogether if it appears unlikely to be successful.
Standard
economic appraisal normally assesses the performance of the project
over its whole lifecycle without taking account of the value of this
flexibility. Averaging the outcomes across multiple scenarios will tend
to undervalue projects, because it does not take account of the ways in
which projects can be adapted to adjust as these various scenarios
arise over time. The advantage of ROA is that it can incorporate the
value of this flexibility, and can therefore lead to better decision
making (HMT, 2007).
ROA can be carried out in a
variety of ways. The most relevant to adaptation is an approach called
dynamic programming which is essentially an extension of decision-tree
analysis. This defines possible outcomes, and assigns probabilities to
these.
The decision-tree defines how a
decision-maker responds to resolution of uncertainty at each branching
point in the tree. Quantifying the value of these decision options then
proceeds by assessing all the branches. ROA calculates option value
based on the expected value over all branches contingent on making the
optimal choice being taken at each decision-point.
The
optimal decision in turn is evaluated based on all the possible
outcomes downstream of that decision in the tree. This ROA value can be
compared to a normal economic (cost-benefit) calculation that would
simply be a probabilityweighted average of the outcomes along each
possible branch in the tree.
Box 1: The
Concepts of Real Options AnalysisThe
example below shows a simplified investment example, showing the
expected gross margin over time, with annuitized capital costs shown as
a blue shaded area. Uncertainty is represented as an anticipated shock
or an information event that occurs in the future (Tp) which will
affect the project’s cash flow either adversely (the red
line) or favourably (the green line). In case A (top) – the
normal positive NPV criterion – a decision has to be made at
time t=0 on whether or not to invest. In this case, there is not the
option to wait. The expected ‘best guess’ (the
central orange line) is the average of the upper and lower estimate of
the outcome of the price shock, noting in this case, risks are
symmetrical, and cancel out such that the expected value of project
will continue to be profitable (and thus the decision maker should
proceed with the investment). In Case B (bottom), there is the
opportunity to wait until time Tp before making the investment. This
allows it to avoid the potential loss that might occur if conditions
turn out worse than expected (the red dashed area), but this must be
traded off against the opportunity costs of waiting (the orange dashed
area).
Case A: “Now
or never” investment option at t=0 |
|
Case B: Option
to wait until after t=Tp, the expected time of policy change
that affects the investment |
|
The
associated decision tree for this example is shown below. The
‘risk event’ represents an event in which a
variable which was previously uncertain is resolved. In this example,
there are only two equivalent outcomes, a high revenue scenario and a
low revenue scenario, noting in practice, there may be many outcomes,
with different probabilities.
To make a direct
comparison between the ‘invest now’ and the
‘wait’ options, the expected net returns (the
probability weighted mean) is expressed in present value terms, since
the decisionmaker needs to compare the relative value of the two
options in the current time period of the decision. Under the
‘invest now’ branch, the expected net return in
present value terms is €25m, since revenue starts to flow
immediately. Under the ‘wait’ branch, the expected
net returns of €37.5m needs to be discounted. If the duration
of the wait was 3 years, and a discount rate of 7% is used, then the
present value would be €30.6m. In this case, the
decision-maker would better off waiting. If the duration of the wait
was 8 years, at 7% discount rate, the present value of the investment
option would be €22m, so the decision-maker in this case would
be better off to invest immediately, and take the future downside risk
when it occurs.