You are here: Home / Pathfinder / Context for this guidance / Ways of framing adaptation

Ways of framing adaptation

This subsection reviews the main ways that climate adaptation is framed both in the scientific literature as well as in practise.

The IPCC definition


The IPCC defines adaptation as “adjustment in natural or human systems to a new or changing environment. Adaptation to climate change refers to adjustment in natural or human systems in response to actual or expected climatic stimuli or their effects, which moderates harm or exploits beneficial opportunities” (McCarthy et al., 2001). In this guideline, we restrict the definition of adaptation to those “adjustments in natural or human systems ...” that are induced by humans themselves, excluding autonomous adaptation of the natural system (i.e., the natural system adapting itself). Restricting the definition of adaptation to human activity, including the human activity of managing natural systems, makes sense because this is the way adaptation is predominately used within the policy and practitioner communities. This does not mean that we consider studying autonomous adaptation of natural systems to be less important, but we only do not call this process adaptation.

Under this broad definition of adaptation, a diversity of approaches are applied for assessing adaptation and several different ways of framing adaptation can be distinguished.

Adaptation as response to climate impacts


The “classical” framing of adaptation in the context of the IPCC is the impact-analytical one, which sees adaptation as a single decision (or as a few single decisions) that is (are) taken on the basis of projected future impacts. The IPCC defines climate change impact assessment as “the practice of identifying and evaluating, in monetary and/or non-monetary terms, the effects of climate change on natural and human systems" (Parry et al., 2007). The basic assumptions are that impacts and adaptation decisions can be singled out and be represented formally by means of mathematical or computational models. Emission scenarios are fed into climate models to produce climate scenarios which are then downscaled to a regional level and fed into impact models to estimate potential impacts. Based on the simulated potential impacts, adaptation measures are identified and evaluated via multi-criteria, costeffectiveness or cost-benefit analysis (Carter et al., 1994, 2007; Adger et al., 2007).

Several limitations of the impact-analystical approach have become apparent and are increasingly motivating other approaches. Opponents of the impact-analytical approach criticise that both impacts and the effects of adaptation options are difficult to predict or project (e.g., van Aalst et al., 2008). Regional climate models exhibit high uncertainties and often show no coherence in results for specific regions (IPCC, 2007). Impact models are only available for some sectors (e.g., agriculture, forestry) and, if available, exhibit similar uncertainties. For many of the world’s regions this means that there is little or no agreement on how the regional climate will change and what impacts to expect.

Adaptation as decision making under uncertainty


In recent years, approaches that frame adaptation from the perspective of decision making under uncertainty have received more attention. In this framing, the analysis does not start with climate scenarios and the projection of impacts, but with a concrete decision (e.g., by how much to raise the dikes), based upon which then all available information on the full range of possible impacts is collected. Climate scenarios may only play a limited role in this framing, as other sources of uncertainty might be more significant (Dessai et al., 2005). Policy documents emphasise so-called no-regret, low-regret or robust options, that is the implementation of options that are beneficial or robust no matter how the climate changes (e.g., European Commission, 2009).

One approach that is particularly relevant under this framing is robust decision making. Uncertainty about mid to long term impacts will continue to make the construction of probability density functions for impacts problematic (Adger et al., 2009). Robust-decision making requires running a large amount of scenarios (without probability attached) and analysing alternatives over these scenarios on a given set of criteria. It does not require probability functions to the different scenarios. This way options can be eliminated which do not perform well in projected futures, even when the likelihoods of future evolutions are not well known. For example, Wilby and Dessai (2010) apply a method of robust decision-making to address the question of ranking adaptation options in the water sector in Wales and
the UK.

Adaptation as a social and institutional process


A further argument made against the impact and decision-analytical approach to adaptation is that even when effective, robust or low-regret adaptation options can be identified, this does not meant that these options are also realised. In many cases it is found that institutional barriers prohibit the implementation of options or that “existing” adaptive capacity is not realised (Adger et al., 2007).

This has led to institution-analytical approaches, which frame adaptation as a social and institutional process that involves many actors and many decisions at different levels. The basic assumptions are that impact and adaptation decisions can not necessarily be singled out and even if they can not be represented formally. Outcomes of actions can usually not be predicted because they depend on actions of (many) other agents as well as the social and cultural context. The focal point of analysis thus are institutions, in the broad sense of “formal and informal rules in use” (Ostrom, 2005), that shape the interplay between the actors. Various variants of this framing can be found in the literature.

Adaptation as reducing current social vulnerability or enhancing adaptive capacity


On a local or community level, a variety of participatory or so-called community-based approaches under the names of Vulnerability and Capacity Assessment (VCA), Livelihood analysis, Rapid Rural Appraisal (RRA) and Participatory Rural Appraisal (PRA) are applied (Chambers, 1994). These assessments emphasise social conditions, individual perceptions and informal institutions in that they build on local experiences in coping (or not coping) with current climate conditions as a starting point for developing appropriate adaptation responses (Pelling and High, 2005; van Aalst et al., 2008).

Adaptation as policy integration/mainstreaming


On the level of national and international policy making, institution-analytical approaches emphasise the need for horizontal integration of policy, which is often also called mainstreaming adaptation or climate-proofing policies. The idea behind these concepts is to integrate (or mainstream) climate change adaptation considerations into existing policy processes. Mainstreaming adaptation was first discussed in the context of development policy (Klein et al., 1995, 2007), but now receives attention in other policy fields. The current European Commission’s White Paper on Adaptation, for example, stresses the integration of adaptation considerations into existing and future policy, legislation and funding programmes (European Commission, 2009).

Adaptation as multi-level governance


Recently, concepts from the domains of governance and adaptive management are receiving broader attention in climate change adaptation. The concept of multi-level governance stresses both vertical and horizontal integration of policy. It acknowledges that (i) policy fields are increasingly difficult to separate, (ii) that the influence of private or non-state actors is increasing, and (iii) that decisions are less-top down. Outcomes are thus determined by the interplay of intuitions at various levels of decision making and multilevel institutions are seen to be key to adaptation and sustainability (Adger et al., 2005; Anderies et al., 2005; Berkes, 2007; Armitage et al., 2008).

Adaptation as (social) learning and adaptive management


The concept of adaptive management (AM) has emerged as a response to the complexity and non-determinism inherent in many resource management situations (Holling, 1973; Walters, 1986) and is seen as an instrument to bridge the gap between adaptation research and policy (Arvai et al., 2006). AM is the process of improving management goals, policies and practises through learning from the outcomes of management (Pahl-Wostl et al., 2007). Rather than attempting to generate more knowledge about regional climate change, impacts and adaptation options via analytical methods, adaptive management builds on the ability of institutions to adapt ad-hoc when experiencing environmental (or social) change (Dietz et al., 2003; Pahl-Wostl et al., 2007; Huitema et al., 2009). Institutions are not designed specifically in response to climate change or other threats but are designed to be adaptive in general through their ability to experiment and learn. AM is thus closely connected to the concepts of social and institutional learning (Armitage et al., 2008).

Next to the ability to learn, the AM literature emphasises, further generic properties of institutions that makes them adaptive (Huitema et al., 2009). Polycentric institutions are seen to be adaptive because rights and responsibilities are distributed between different “centres” thus allowing for redundancy, diversity and experimentation, which, in turn, helps to better cope with change and uncertainty (Dietz et al., 2003; Ostrom, 2005). Other literature emphasises “institutional fit”, which refers to the matching of the institutional arrangement to the bio-physical scale of the socio-ecological system that is being managed (Young, 2002). The evidence about the effectiveness of institutions designed according to these properties is, however, weak as it is generally difficult to attribute outcomes to particular institutions (Huitema et al., 2009). It is widely accepted that there are no panaceas to institutional design (Ostrom, 2007, 2009).