Cost-Effectiveness Analysis (CEA) is a widely used decision
support tool. It compares alternative options for achieving similar
outputs (or objectives). In this regard it is a relative measure,
providing comparative information between choices. It has been widely
used in environmental policy analysis, because it avoids monetary
valuation of benefits, and instead quantifies benefits in physical
terms.
At the
technical or project level, CEA can
be used to compare and rank alternative options. It does this by
assessing options in terms of the cost per unit of benefit delivered,
e.g. cost per tonne of pollution abated. This identifies those options
that deliver highest benefit for lowest cost (i.e. the most
cost-effective). As well as ranking different options, such an analysis
can be used for benchmarking, see box.
At the
project, policy or programme level,
where combinations of options are needed, CEA can be used to assess the
most cost-effective order of options, and so identify the least-cost
path for achieving pre-defined policy targets. This is
undertaken through the use of marginal abatement cost (MAC)
curves. The approach can also identify the largest benefits possible
with the available resources, and can even be used to help set targets,
by selecting the point where cost-effectiveness falls significantly
(i.e. where there are disproportionately high costs for low benefits).
Box 1. Benchmarking using CEA
Cost-effectiveness
analysis can be used to benchmark options, i.e. by setting thresholds.
This approach is often used in considering new treatments in health
service provision (e.g. in the UK), where the clinic effectiveness of
new interventions are compared against a cost-effectiveness threshold,
measured as the cost (£) per Quality Adjusted Life Year
(QALY). New treatments or drugs are considered cost-effective if they
are lower than £20 000 to £30 000 per QALY (NICE,
2010). Such an approach is needed because publicly funded healthcare
systems cannot pay for every new medical treatment that becomes
available. As there are limited resources, choices have to be made,
cost-effectiveness analysis helps provide the largest benefits with the
available resources.
Box 2. Comparing Mitigation and
Adaptation
Cost-effectiveness
analysis has become the primary appraisal method for mitigation.
However, adaptation is very different to mitigation, for the following
reasons:
Mitigation
involves a single, common metric for benefits, i.e. tonnes of GHG
emissions. This metric relates to a global burden, so a
reduction in a tonne of GHG emissions is treated the same, irrespective
of the technology, sector or location. This means a tonne of CO2 abated
from road transport in an urban area has the same benefit (and unit of
effectiveness) as a tonne abated from the electricity sector in a rural
location. This allows equivalent cross-economy analysis of options
using €/tCO2.
In contrast, adaptation is a
response to a local, regional or national level impact, rather than
to a global burden, and involves different types of risks in different
sectors. There is therefore no common single metric which allows
cross-sectoral cost-effectiveness analysis. Furthermore, there are
often many risks even within a single sector, which can make even
sectoral CEA studies challenging: for example, adaptation to sea level
rise (SLR) can involve protecting people from flood risk, reducing
coastal erosion, conserving coastal ecosystems, etc. all of which
involve different metrics. Finally, the analysis of impacts in
adaptation (rather than burdens in mitigation) means that technology,
location and time period are important: for adaptation, it makes a
different how, where and when cost-effectiveness is assessed.
Cost-effectiveness
analysis has been widely used in European and Member State policy
appraisal, and was previously the main approach used for air quality
policy (Watkiss et al, 2007). Air quality concentration or deposition
target levels were set on a scientific basis, and the costs of
alternative ways of achieving these targets (or progressing towards
them) were assessed using CEA.
It has also been
used in risk-based flood protection assessment, particularly for
coastal zones (e.g. RIVM, 2004) assessing the costeffectiveness of
achieving flood protection targets (defined as a level of acceptable
risk, such as protection against a 1 in 10000 year return period).
Most
recently, cost-effectiveness analysis has become the main appraisal
technique used for climate change
mitigation,
as it allows the comparison and ranking of greenhouse gas (GHG)
abatement options, using the costeffectiveness metric of cost per tonne
of GHG abated (€/tCO2). There has also been widespread use of
marginal abatement cost curves for mitigation. These show the relative
ranking of options in order of cost-effectiveness, and can be used for
identifying the least cost way of achieving emission reductions
including cross-economy targets (e.g. CCC, 2008).
Because
of the widespread use of CEA for climate change mitigation, many
commentators have also highlighted its potential use for climate change
adaptation. However, the application of CEA to adaptation involves a
number of major differences, see Box 2.
Cost-effectiveness
analysis involves a series of common methodological steps.
- Establish
the effectiveness criteria.
- Collate a list of
options.
- Collect cost data for each option
– noting this involves the full costs over the
lifetime of the option, including capital and operating costs
– and thus requires all values to be
expressed on a common economic basis (in
equivalent terms using discount rates and either
an equivalent annualised cost or a total
present value).
- Assess the potential
benefits (effectiveness) of each option. In many but not all,
these are expressed as an annual benefit, relative to
a baseline or reference case.
- Combine
these to estimate the costeffectiveness, by dividing the
lifetime cost by the lifetime benefit (or annualised costs
by annualised benefit).
At this point,
all the options can be expressed in equivalent terms, as a cost per
unit of effectiveness. This allows the ranking of measures, identifying
the most costeffectiveness options, i.e. those that deliver high
benefits for low costs.
This information can
then be used as an input to form a marginal abatement cost curve. Cost
curves have been used for many decades in policy (and mitigation)
analysis. In graphical terms, they are often presented as cumulative
bar charts.
In simple terms, a cost curve
presents all options in order of unit cost-effectiveness analysis,
starting with the most cost-effective. At the same time, it also
assesses the total cumulative effectiveness of each option, as it is
added. When considered together, this allows the estimation of the
least-cost way to achieve a plan, programme or policy target /objective.
An
example is included below, showing a typical mitigation cost curve.
Each bar represents a specific option. The options are arranged in
order of cost-effectiveness (left to right), as measured on the
vertical axis by the cost per unit of abatement –
€/CO2. The width of each bar indicates the total abatement
potential of each option (i.e. the total effectiveness, in tonnes of
CO2) – noting this could be for a local plan or a national
level analysis. Wider bars show options that can achieve larger total
benefits, i.e. which reduce more emissions. In the example, the
marginal abatement costs of some cost-effective options are negative,
showing these achieve benefits at negative cost, so called no regret
options (e.g. energy efficiency).
Example cost curve.To undertake a policy CEA, a
target level of total effectiveness is first set and the cost curve is
generated. As the graph presents options in order of
cost-effectiveness, it estimates the cumulative least-cost pathway to
achieve the target, because it implements those options that have high
benefits for low cost first. By contrast, if the least cost-effective
options were implemented first (those on the right of the figure), it
would cost far more to achieve the same target level.
The
combination of options needed to achieve the target can thus be read
off the graph. A similar approach can be used to derive the total costs
of different levels of ambition. In practice, CEA is more involved, and
further checks are needed to ensure that options can be implemented
together, and to consider other criteria.